Making Sense of Gentrification

Last week, we read Lance Freeman’s chapter “Making Sense of Gentrification.” He provides first hand experiences of residents of Clinton Hill and Harlem that allow for the analyzation of gentrification in urban spaces. He explains that gentrification can be examined by focusing on both the demand and supply side of urban living. In other words, gentrification can be attributed to shifts in consumer preferences and the cyclical nature of capital and its constant search for the highest rate of return. Hence, historically black neighborhoods are becoming much more white, and this racial/class change comes with many implications like whites demand for better resources. In class, I discussed the ways in which we see the “improvements” occurring in these gentrified spaces. However, I want to specifically discuss how gentrification can be attributed to the fluctuating relationship among capital investments and the production of urban space (the Economic Process Theory).

As the population of the world increases, cities are increasingly expanding to allow housing for new residents who have jobs in these metropolitan areas. However, as the new urban middle class has proven to us, there is an increasing desire to be close to the city center. Even though the 20th century was a time where a suburban lifestyle was desired, the new generation of middle class individuals have shown a higher tendency to prefer urban living.

An important aspect in defining and observing gentrification is the way in which capital flows into a place. Freeman particularly analyzes Clinton Hill and Harlem as places that have experienced gentrification. In his chapter, he discusses the neighborhoods that surround these two historically black neighborhoods. Places like West Chester and Cobble Hill have very high housing prices. However, housing prices are much lower in Clinton Hill and Harlem. Therefore, to real estate agents, business owners, and political figures these low costs are what excited a lot of potential for these places.  

The economic process theory shows us how land amenities like a particular landscape, certain natural resources, or the historicity of a place can lead to economic opportunities and investment. In the case of Harlem and Clinton Hill, it is clear that these neighborhoods have a great location in terms of being close to Manhattan, but with historic brownstones lined up and down the streets. To investors and potential home buyers, it is an attractive space with low housing costs, but all the same amenities as a more expensive neighborhood. Furthermore, as real estate agents soon started to market and sell housing in these neighborhoods, the cultural and physical dynamic of these places changed. In other words, gentrification had begun.

As the new urban middle class moved into Harlem and Clinton Hill, they did not stay silent about the lack of middle class amenities in their new adopted home. This demand for better resources was met with business owners opening stores and providing a market for a wealthier audience. However, existing residents of these places still had a lack of capital that allowed them to purchase items at the same places the new urban middle class individuals shopped at. Nonetheless, it is important to realize the way capital contributes to these changes. Because middle class individuals have different preferences and are able to purchase more luxury items, they will always be met with suppliers that provide these items.

I believe the economic process theory is a very interesting way of thinking about gentrification. There will always be a demand and supply side of housing, and this relationship determines what economic opportunities will stem from it. Also, this post was not meant to look past all the other factors that contribute to gentrification. It was instead to focus on one particular relationship between consumers and producers of place.